f Daniel Gilbert is right, then you are
wrong. That is to say, if Daniel Gilbert is right, then you are wrong to
believe that a new car will make you as happy as you imagine. You are
wrong to believe that a new kitchen will make you happy for as long as you
imagine. You are wrong to think that you will be more unhappy with a big
single setback (a broken wrist, a broken heart) than with a lesser chronic
one (a trick knee, a tense marriage). You are wrong to assume that job
failure will be crushing. You are wrong to expect that a death in the
family will leave you bereft for year upon year, forever and ever. You are
even wrong to reckon that a cheeseburger you order in a restaurant -- this
week, next week, a year from now, it doesn't really matter when -- will
definitely hit the spot. That's because when it comes to predicting
exactly how you will feel in the future, you are most likely wrong.
A professor in Harvard's department of psychology, Gilbert likes to
tell people that he studies happiness. But it would be more precise to say
that Gilbert -- along with the psychologist Tim Wilson of the University
of Virginia, the economist George Loewenstein of Carnegie-Mellon and the
psychologist (and Nobel laureate in economics) Daniel Kahneman of
Princeton -- has taken the lead in studying a specific type of emotional
and behavioral prediction. In the past few years, these four men have
begun to question the decision-making process that shapes our sense of
well-being: how do we predict what will make us happy or unhappy -- and
then how do we feel after the actual experience? For example, how do we
suppose we'll feel if our favorite college football team wins or loses,
and then how do we really feel a few days after the game? How do we
predict we'll feel about purchasing jewelry, having children, buying a big
house or being rich? And then how do we regard the outcomes? According to
this small corps of academics, almost all actions -- the decision to buy
jewelry, have kids, buy the big house or work exhaustively for a fatter
paycheck -- are based on our predictions of the emotional consequences of
these events.
Until recently, this was uncharted territory. How we forecast our
feelings, and whether those predictions match our future emotional states,
had never been the stuff of laboratory research. But in scores of
experiments, Gilbert, Wilson, Kahneman and Loewenstein have made a slew of
observations and conclusions that undermine a number of fundamental
assumptions: namely, that we humans understand what we want and are adept
at improving our well-being -- that we are good at maximizing our utility,
in the jargon of traditional economics. Further, their work on prediction
raises some unsettling and somewhat more personal questions. To understand
affective forecasting, as Gilbert has termed these studies, is to wonder
if everything you have ever thought about life choices, and about
happiness, has been at the least somewhat naive and, at worst, greatly
mistaken.
The problem, as Gilbert and company have come to discover, is that we
falter when it comes to imagining how we will feel about something in the
future. It isn't that we get the big things wrong. We know we will
experience visits to Le Cirque and to the periodontist differently; we can
accurately predict that we'd rather be stuck in Montauk than in a Midtown
elevator. What Gilbert has found, however, is that we overestimate the
intensity and the duration of our emotional reactions -- our ''affect'' --
to future events. In other words, we might believe that a new BMW will
make life perfect. But it will almost certainly be less exciting than we
anticipated; nor will it excite us for as long as predicted. The vast
majority of Gilbert's test participants through the years have
consistently made just these sorts of errors both in the laboratory and in
real-life situations. And whether Gilbert's subjects were trying to
predict how they would feel in the future about a plate of spaghetti with
meat sauce, the defeat of a preferred political candidate or romantic
rejection seemed not to matter. On average, bad events proved less intense
and more transient than test participants predicted. Good events proved
less intense and briefer as well.
Gilbert and his collaborator Tim Wilson call the gap between what we
predict and what we ultimately experience the ''impact bias'' --
''impact'' meaning the errors we make in estimating both the intensity and
duration of our emotions and ''bias'' our tendency to err. The phrase
characterizes how we experience the dimming excitement over not just a BMW
but also over any object or event that we presume will make us happy.
Would a 20 percent raise or winning the lottery result in a contented
life? You may predict it will, but almost surely it won't turn out that
way. And a new plasma television? You may have high hopes, but the impact
bias suggests that it will almost certainly be less cool, and in a shorter
time, than you imagine. Worse, Gilbert has noted that these mistakes of
expectation can lead directly to mistakes in choosing what we think will
give us pleasure. He calls this ''miswanting.''
''The average person says, 'I know I'll be happier with a Porsche than a Chevy,' '' Gilbert explains. ''
'Or with Linda rather than Rosalyn. Or as a doctor rather than as a
plumber.' That seems very clear to people. The problem is, I can't get
into medical school or afford the Porsche. So for the average person, the
obstacle between them and happiness is actually getting the futures that
they desire. But what our research shows -- not just ours, but
Loewenstein's and Kahneman's -- is that the real problem is figuring out
which of those futures is going to have the high payoff and is really
going to make you happy.
''You know, the Stones said, 'You can't always get what you want,' ''
Gilbert adds. ''I don't think that's the problem. The problem is you can't
always know what you want.''
Gilbert's papers on affective forecasting began to appear in the
late 1990's, but the idea to study happiness and emotional prediction
actually came to him on a sunny afternoon in October 1992, just as he and
his friend Jonathan Jay Koehler sat down for lunch outside the psychology
building at the University of Texas at Austin, where both men were
teaching at the time. Gilbert was uninspired about his studies and says he
felt despair about his failing marriage. And as he launched into a
discussion of his personal life, he swerved to ask why economists focus on
the financial aspects of decision making rather than the emotional ones.
Koehler recalls, ''Gilbert said something like: 'It all seems so small. It
isn't really about money; it's about happiness. Isn't that what everybody
wants to know when we make a decision?' '' For a moment, Gilbert forgot
his troubles, and two more questions came to him. Do we even know what
makes us happy? And if it's difficult to figure out what makes us happy in
the moment, how can we predict what will make us happy in the future?
In the early 1990's, for an up-and-coming psychology professor like
Gilbert to switch his field of inquiry from how we perceive one another to
happiness, as he did that day, was just a hairsbreadth short of bizarre.
But Gilbert has always liked questions that lead him somewhere new. Now
45, Gilbert dropped out of high school at 15, hooking into what he calls
''the tail end of the hippie movement'' and hitchhiking aimlessly from
town to town with his guitar. He met his wife on the road; she was
hitching in the other direction. They married at 17, had a son at 18 and
settled down in Denver. ''I pulled weeds, I sold rebar, I sold carpet, I
installed carpet, I spent a lot of time as a phone solicitor,'' he
recalls. During this period he spent several years turning out
science-fiction stories for magazines like Amazing Stories. Thus, in
addition to being ''one of the most gifted social psychologists of our
age,'' as the psychology writer and professor David G. Myers describes him
to me, Gilbert is the author of ''The Essence of Grunk,'' a story about an
encounter with a creature made of egg salad that jets around the galaxy in
a rocket-powered refrigerator.
Psychology was a matter of happenstance. In the midst of his sci-fi
career, Gilbert tried to sign up for a writing course at the local
community college, but the class was full; he figured that psych, still
accepting registrants, would help him with character development in his
fiction. It led instead to an undergraduate degree at the University of
Colorado at Denver, then a Ph.D. at Princeton, then an appointment at the
University of Texas, then the appointment at Harvard. ''People ask why I
study happiness,'' Gilbert says, ''and I say, 'Why study anything else?'
It's the holy grail. We're studying the thing that all human action is
directed toward.''
One experiment of Gilbert's had students in a photography class at
Harvard choose two favorite pictures from among those they had just taken
and then relinquish one to the teacher. Some students were told their
choices were permanent; others were told they could exchange their prints
after several days. As it turned out, those who had time to change their
minds were less pleased with their decisions than those whose choices were
irrevocable.
Much of Gilbert's research is in this vein. Another recent study asked
whether transit riders in Boston who narrowly missed their trains
experienced the self-blame that people tend to predict they'll feel in
this situation. (They did not.) And a paper waiting to be published, ''The
Peculiar Longevity of Things Not So Bad,'' examines why we expect that
bigger problems will always dwarf minor annoyances. ''When really bad
things happen to us, we defend against them,'' Gilbert explains. ''People,
of course, predict the exact opposite. If you ask, 'What would you rather
have, a broken leg or a trick knee?' they'd probably say, 'Trick knee.'
And yet, if your goal is to accumulate maximum happiness over your
lifetime, you just made the wrong choice. A trick knee is a bad thing to
have.''
All of these studies establish the links between prediction, decision
making and well-being. The photography experiment challenges our common
assumption that we would be happier with the option to change our minds
when in fact we're happier with closure. The transit experiment
demonstrates that we tend to err in estimating our regret over missed
opportunities. The ''things not so bad'' work shows our failure to imagine
how grievously irritations compromise our satisfaction. Our emotional
defenses snap into action when it comes to a divorce or a disease but not
for lesser problems. We fix the leaky roof on our house, but over the long
haul, the broken screen door we never mend adds up to more frustration.
Gilbert does not believe all forecasting mistakes lead to similar
results; a death in the family, a new gym membership and a new husband are
not the same, but in how they affect our well-being they are similar.
''Our research simply says that whether it's the thing that matters or the
thing that doesn't, both of them matter less than you think they will,''
he says. ''Things that happen to you or that you buy or own -- as much as
you think they make a difference to your happiness, you're wrong by a
certain amount. You're overestimating how much of a difference they make.
None of them make the difference you think. And that's true of positive
and negative events.''
uch of the work of Kahneman, Loewenstein, Gilbert and Wilson
takes its cue from the concept of adaptation, a term psychologists have
used since at least the 1950's to refer to how we acclimate to changing
circumstances. George Loewenstein sums up this human capacity as follows:
''Happiness is a signal that our brains use to motivate us to do certain
things. And in the same way that our eye adapts to different levels of
illumination, we're designed to kind of go back to the happiness set
point. Our brains are not trying to be happy. Our brains are trying to
regulate us.'' In this respect, the tendency toward adaptation suggests
why the impact bias is so pervasive. As Tim Wilson says: ''We don't
realize how quickly we will adapt to a pleasurable event and make it the
backdrop of our lives. When any event occurs to us, we make it ordinary.
And through becoming ordinary, we lose our pleasure.''
It is easy to overlook something new and crucial in what Wilson is
saying. Not that we invariably lose interest in bright and shiny things
over time -- this is a long-known trait -- but that we're generally unable
to recognize that we adapt to new circumstances and therefore fail to
incorporate this fact into our decisions. So, yes, we will adapt to the
BMW and the plasma TV, since we adapt to virtually everything. But Wilson
and Gilbert and others have shown that we seem unable to predict that we
will adapt. Thus, when we find the pleasure derived from a thing
diminishing, we move on to the next thing or event and almost certainly
make another error of prediction, and then another, ad infinitum.
As Gilbert points out, this glitch is also significant when it comes to
negative events like losing a job or the death of someone we love, in
response to which we project a permanently inconsolable future. ''The
thing I'm most interested in, that I've spent the most time studying, is
our failure to recognize how powerful psychological defenses are once
they're activated,'' Gilbert says. ''We've used the metaphor of the
'psychological immune system' -- it's just a metaphor, but not a bad one
for that system of defenses that helps you feel better when bad things
happen. Observers of the human condition since Aristotle have known that
people have these defenses. Freud spent his life, and his daughter Anna
spent her life, worrying about these defenses. What's surprising is that
people don't seem to recognize that they have these defenses, and
that these defenses will be triggered by negative events.'' During the
course of my interviews with Gilbert, a close friend of his died. ''I am
like everyone in thinking, I'll never get over this and life will never be
good again,'' he wrote to me in an e-mail message as he planned a trip to
Texas for the funeral. ''But because of my work, there is always a voice
in the back of my head -- a voice that wears a lab coat and has a lot of
data tucked under its arm -- that says, 'Yes, you will, and yes, it will.'
And I know that voice is right.''
Still, the argument that we imperfectly imagine what we want and how we
will cope is nevertheless disorienting. On the one hand, it can cast a
shadow of regret on some life decisions. Why did I decide that working 100
hours a week to earn more would make me happy? Why did I think retiring to
Sun City, Ariz., would please me? On the other hand, it can be
enlightening. No wonder this teak patio set hasn't made me as happy as I
expected. Even if she dumps me, I'll be O.K. Either way, predicting how
things will feel to us over the long term is mystifying. A large body of
research on well-being seems to suggest that wealth above middle-class
comfort makes little difference to our happiness, for example, or that
having children does nothing to improve well-being -- even as it drives
marital satisfaction dramatically down. We often yearn for a roomy,
isolated home (a thing we easily adapt to), when, in fact, it will
probably compromise our happiness by distancing us from neighbors. (Social
interaction and friendships have been shown to give lasting pleasure.) The
big isolated home is what Loewenstein, 48, himself bought. ''I fell into a
trap I never should have fallen into,'' he told me.
Loewenstein's office is up a narrow stairway in a hidden corner of an
enormous, worn brick building on the edge of the Carnegie-Mellon campus in
Pittsburgh. He and Gilbert make for an interesting contrast. Gilbert is
garrulous, theatrical, dazzling in his speech and writing; he fills a
room. Loewenstein is soft-spoken, given to abstraction and lithe in the
way of a hard-core athlete; he seems to float around a room. Both men
profess tremendous admiration for the other, and their different
disciplines -- psychology and economics -- have made their overlapping
interests in affective forecasting more complementary than fraught. While
Gilbert's most notable contribution to affective forecasting is the impact
bias, Loewenstein's is something called the ''empathy gap.''
Here's how it expresses itself. In a recent experiment, Loewenstein
tried to find out how likely people might be to dance alone to Rick
James's ''Super Freak'' in front of a large audience. Many agreed to do so
for a certain amount of money a week in advance, only to renege when the
day came to take the stage. This sounds like a goof, but it gets at the
fundamental difference between how we behave in ''hot'' states (those of
anxiety, courage, fear, drug craving, sexual excitation and the like) and
''cold'' states of rational calm. This empathy gap in thought and behavior
-- we cannot seem to predict how we will behave in a hot state when we are
in a cold state -- affects happiness in an important but somewhat less
consistent way than the impact bias. ''So much of our lives involves
making decisions that have consequences for the future,'' Loewenstein
says. ''And if our decision making is influenced by these transient
emotional and psychological states, then we know we're not making
decisions with an eye toward future consequences.'' This may be as simple
as an unfortunate proclamation of love in a moment of lust, Loewenstein
explains, or something darker, like an act of road rage or of suicide.
Among other things, this line of inquiry has led Loewenstein to
collaborate with health experts looking into why people engage in
unprotected sex when they would never agree to do so in moments of cool
calculation. Data from tests in which volunteers are asked how they would
behave in various ''heat of the moment'' situations -- whether they would
have sex with a minor, for instance, or act forcefully with a partner who
asks them to stop -- have consistently shown that different states of
arousal can alter answers by astonishing margins. ''These kinds of states
have the ability to change us so profoundly that we're more different from
ourselves in different states than we are from another person,''
Loewenstein says.
Part of Loewenstein's curiosity about hot and cold states comes from
situations in which his emotions have been pitted against his intellect.
When he's not teaching, he treks around the world, making sure to get to
Alaska to hike or kayak at least once a year. A scholar of mountaineering
literature, he once wrote a paper that examined why climbers have a poor
memory for pain and usually ignore turn-back times at great peril. But he
has done the same thing himself many times. He almost died in a whitewater
canoeing accident and vowed afterward that he never wanted to see his
runaway canoe again. (A couple of hours later, he went looking for it.)
The same goes for his climbing pursuits. ''You establish your turn-back
time, and then you find yourself still far from the peak,'' he says. ''So
you push on. You haven't brought enough food or clothes, and then as a
result, you're stuck at 13,000 feet, and you have to just sit there and
shiver all night without a sleeping bag or warm clothes. When the sun
comes up, you're half-frozen, and you say, 'Never again.' Then you get
back and immediately start craving getting out again.'' He pushes the
point: ''I have tried to train my emotions.'' But he admits that he may
make the same mistakes on his next trip.
ould a world without forecasting errors be a better world?
Would a life lived without forecasting errors be a richer life? Among the
academics who study affective forecasting, there seems little doubt that
these sorts of questions will ultimately jump from the academy to the real
world. ''If people do not know what is going to make them better off or
give them pleasure,'' Daniel Kahneman says, ''then the idea that you can
trust people to do what will give them pleasure becomes questionable.'' To
Kahneman, who did some of the first experiments in the area in the early
1990's, affective forecasting could greatly influence retirement planning,
for example, where mistakes in prediction (how much we save, how much we
spend, how we choose a community we think we'll enjoy) can prove
irreversible. He sees a role for affective forecasting in consumer
spending, where a ''cooling off'' period might remedy buyer's remorse.
Most important, he sees vital applications in health care, especially when
it comes to informed consent. ''We consider people capable of giving
informed consent once they are told of the objective effects of a
treatment,'' Kahneman says. ''But can people anticipate how they and other
people will react to a colostomy or to the removal of their vocal cords?
The research on affective forecasting suggests that people may have little
ability to anticipate their adaptation beyond the early stages.''
Loewenstein, along with his collaborator Dr. Peter Ubel, has done a great
deal of work showing that nonpatients overestimate the displeasure of
living with the loss of a limb, for instance, or paraplegia. To use
affective forecasting to prove that people adapt to serious physical
challenges far better and will be happier than they imagine, Loewenstein
says, could prove invaluable.
There are downsides to making public policy in light of this research,
too. While walking in Pittsburgh one afternoon, Loewenstein tells me that
he doesn't see how anybody could study happiness and not find himself
leaning left politically; the data make it all too clear that boosting the
living standards of those already comfortable, such as through lower
taxes, does little to improve their levels of well-being, whereas raising
the living standards of the impoverished makes an enormous difference.
Nevertheless, he and Gilbert (who once declared in an academic paper,
''Windfalls are better than pratfalls, A's are better than C's, December
25 is better than April 15, and everything is better than a Republican
administration'') seem to lean libertarian in regard to pushing any kind
of prescriptive agenda. ''We're very, very nervous about overapplying the
research,'' Loewenstein says. ''Just because we figure out that X makes
people happy and they're choosing Y, we don't want to impose X on them. I
have a discomfort with paternalism and with using the results coming out
of our field to impose decisions on people.''
Still, Gilbert and Loewenstein can't contain the personal and
philosophical questions raised by their work. After talking with both men,
I found it hard not to wonder about my own predictions at every turn. At
times it seemed like knowing the secret to some parlor trick that was
nonetheless very difficult to pull off -- when I ogled a new car at the
Honda dealership as I waited for a new muffler on my '92 Accord, for
instance, or as my daughter's fever spiked one evening and I imagined
something terrible, and then something more terrible thereafter. With some
difficulty, I could observe my mind overshooting the mark, zooming past
accuracy toward the sublime or the tragic. It was tempting to want to try
to think about the future more moderately. But it seemed nearly impossible
as well.
To Loewenstein, who is especially attendant to the friction between his
emotional and deliberative processes, a life without forecasting errors
would most likely be a better, happier life. ''If you had a deep
understanding of the impact bias and you acted on it, which is not always
that easy to do, you would tend to invest your resources in the things
that would make you happy,'' he says. This might mean taking more time
with friends instead of more time for making money. He also adds that a
better understanding of the empathy gap -- those hot and cold states we
all find ourselves in on frequent occasions -- could save people from
making regrettable decisions in moments of courage or craving.
Gilbert seems optimistic about using the work in terms of improving
''institutional judgment'' -- how we spend health care dollars, for
example -- but less sanguine about using it to improve our personal
judgment. He admits that he has taken some of his research to heart; for
instance, his work on what he calls the psychological immune system has
led him to believe that he would be able to adapt to even the worst turn
of events. In addition, he says that he now takes more chances in life, a
fact corroborated in at least one aspect by his research partner Tim
Wilson, who says that driving with Gilbert in Boston is a terrifying,
white-knuckle experience. ''But I should have learned many more lessons
from my research than I actually have,'' Gilbert admits. ''I'm getting
married in the spring because this woman is going to make me happy
forever, and I know it.'' At this, Gilbert laughs, a sudden, booming laugh
that fills his Cambridge office. He seems to find it funny not because
it's untrue, but because nothing could be more true. This is how he feels.
''I don't think I want to give up all these motivations,'' he says, ''that
belief that there's the good and there's the bad and that this is a
contest to try to get one and avoid the other. I don't think I want to
learn too much from my research in that sense.''
Even so, Gilbert is currently working on a complex experiment in which
he has made affective forecasting errors ''go away.'' In this test,
Gilbert's team asks members of Group A to estimate how they'll feel if
they receive negative personality feedback. The impact bias kicks in, of
course, and they mostly predict they'll feel terrible, when in fact they
end up feeling O.K. But if Gilbert shows Group B that others have gotten
the same feedback and felt O.K. afterward, then its members predict
they'll feel O.K. as well. The impact bias disappears, and the
participants in Group B make accurate predictions.
This is exciting to Gilbert. But at the same time, it's not a technique
he wants to shape into a self-help book, or one that he even imagines
could be practically implemented. ''Hope and fear are enduring features of
the human experience,'' he says, ''and it is unlikely that people are
going to abandon them anytime soon just because some psychologist told
them they should.'' In fact, in his recent writings, he has wondered
whether forecasting errors might somehow serve a larger functional purpose
he doesn't yet understand. If he could wave a wand tomorrow and eliminate
all affective-forecasting errors, I ask, would he? ''The benefits of not
making this error would seem to be that you get a little more happiness,''
he says. ''When choosing between two jobs, you wouldn't sweat as much
because you'd say: 'You know, I'll be happy in both. I'll adapt to either
circumstance pretty well, so there's no use in killing myself for the next
week.' But maybe our caricatures of the future -- these overinflated
assessments of how good or bad things will be -- maybe it's these illusory
assessments that keep us moving in one direction over the other. Maybe we
don't want a society of people who shrug and say, 'It won't really make a
difference.'
''Maybe it's important for there to be carrots and sticks in the world,
even if they are illusions,'' he adds. ''They keep us moving towards
carrots and away from sticks.''
Jon Gertner is a contributing writer for Money magazine.